Money changes everything How finance made civilization possible

William N. Goetzmann

Book - 2016

Exploring the critical role of finance over the millennia, and around the world, Goetzmann details how wondrous financial technologies and institutions--money, bonds, banks, corporations, and more--have helped urban centers to expand and cultures to flourish. And it's not done reshaping our lives, as Goetzmann considers the challenges we face in the future, such as how to use the power of finance to care for an aging and expanding population.

Saved in:

2nd Floor Show me where

332.49/Goetzmann
1 / 1 copies available
Location Call Number   Status
2nd Floor 332.49/Goetzmann Checked In
Subjects
Published
Princeton : Princeton University Press [2016]
Language
English
Main Author
William N. Goetzmann (author)
Physical Description
viii, 584 pages : illustrations ; 25 cm
Bibliography
Includes bibliographical references and index.
ISBN
9780691143781
  • Part I. From cuneiform to classical civilization
  • 1. Finance and writing
  • 2. Finance and urbanism
  • 3. Financial architecture
  • 4. Mesopotamian twilight
  • 5. Athenian finance
  • 6. Monetary revolution
  • 7. Roman finance
  • Part II. The financial legacy of China
  • 8. China's first financial world
  • 9. Unity and bureaucracy
  • 10. Financial divergence
  • Part III. The European crucible
  • 11. The Temple and finance
  • 12. Venice
  • 13. Fibonacci and finance
  • 14. Immortal bonds
  • 15. The discovery of chance
  • 16. Efficient markets
  • 17. Europa, Inc.
  • 18. Corporations and exploration
  • 19. A projecting age
  • 20. A bubble in France
  • 21. According to Hoyle
  • 22. Securitization and debt
  • Part IV. The emergence of global markets
  • 23. Marx and markets
  • 24. China's financiers
  • 25. The Russian bear
  • 26. Keynes to the rescue
  • 27. The new financial world
  • 28. Re-engineering the future
  • 29. Post-war theory.
Review by Choice Review

The invention of writing, the rise of dynasties in China, the discovery of the New World, and the construction of skyscrapers that dot urban landscapes: in this book, Goetzmann (Yale School of Management) illustrates how finance made these events, and many others, possible. Through 29 chapters spanning four parts, two major themes emerge. One, finance is a time machine, "moving economic value forward and backward through time," and two, finance reallocates risk. The author argues that "the history of finance is an exciting story," and most readers will agree. The book is replete with fascinating historical tales and figures, including an option payoff diagram developed by Henri Lefèvre in the mid-1800s. Well-written and engaging, Goetzmann's book is a wonderful resource for those interested in learning more about the historical role of finance and its potential for addressing future challenges. Summing Up: Recommended. Lower-division undergraduates through faculty. --Julie Fitzpatrick, SUNY Fredonia

Copyright American Library Association, used with permission.
Review by New York Times Review

"THE VERY RICH ARE DIFFERENT from you and me," Ernest Hemingway has F. Scott Fitzgerald write in the original version of "The Snows of Kilimanjaro." "Yes," comes the response, "they have more money." This famous (and wholly fictional) exchange is memorable because it captures so succinctly one of the great fascinations of finance, how it is at one and the same time something so completely mysterious and so utterly banal. It also poses an important question: Does having more money than someone constitute a difference only in quantity, or in quality? Does the increase of financial wealth just make for more of the same - or does it change people in a more essential way? Hemingway was exploring these questions on the level of the individual. William N. Goetzmann, the Edwin J. Beinecke professor of finance and management at Yale, is shooting for bigger game in his new book, "Money Changes Everything: How Finance Made Civilization Possible." His goal is to explore the consequences of the invention and growth of finance for whole societies. As his title suggests, his conclusion is that they are firmly positive. Financially advanced societies, he argues, are very different from financially primitive ones - and not just in that they have more money. The idea that dominates this magnificent history of money and finance, and brings order to the erudite survey of modern research that Goetzmann has marshaled, is that finance is a "technology of civilization" - a way of thinking about and doing things that has been the central facilitator of the material, artistic and cultural accomplishments that we call civilized life. Indeed finance, Goetzmann argues, is a sort of master technology, from which an astonishing range of our most basic habits of mind derives. It is now generally agreed, for example, that in the West both numeracy and literacy were invented not in the context of scientific or artistic pursuits, but in the service of finance and commerce. The peculiar geography and climate of Mesopotamia led in the early third millennium B.C. to the formation of the first great agglomerations of people - sprawling cities at a time when the Mediterranean world could boast only glorified villages. The unprecedented scale of such societies required a revolution in the methods of economic organization. Autarkic subsistence farming had to be replaced by specialization, the division of labor and coordination on a massive scale. The innovation developed by the clerical bureaucracies to enable this transition was the invention of financial accounting. And it was only as part of this new financial system that writing and abstract numbers - those epochal inventions that so clearly transformed the subsequent history of humanity in so many other fields - were invented. If the invention of writing and math is not surprising enough, Goetzmann also argues convincingly that finance is responsible for our modern conception of time. Pre-monetary society operated on sacred time, with the day divided up by ecclesiastical offices or prayer times, and the year into high days and holy days that reflected the cycle of the seasons or the phases of the moon. Financial reasoning and, in particular, the calculation of compound interest demanded a more regimented scheme arbitrated by objective mathematical rules rather than clerical authority. "In essence," as Goetzmann memorably puts it, "financial technology is a time machine" - a set of ideas and practices that enable us to shift economic value backward and forward through time. As a result, we owe to financial innovation conventions as basic as the detachment of the calendar from the astronomical year - the ancient Sumerians introduced a 360-day year in order to make calculating interest easier. Many more of our most fundamental concepts and institutions turn out to be byproducts of financial innovation. Modern ideas of probability and risk, of ethics and morality, and of appropriate models of commercial and even political organization - all were forged in the furnaces of finance, Goetzmann argues. Because financial innovations "changed human behavior," money really can be said to have made the modern world. It is a fascinating thesis, brilliantly illuminated by scores of vivid examples, generously illustrated with a wealth of pictures, comprehensive in its geographical and temporal scope, and in my view almost entirely convincing. There is one aspect of it, however, where both historical evidence and contemporary experience make me less comfortable with Goetzmann's story. Goetzmann views the progress of financial innovation as an example of humans' ingenuity in overcoming technical and material challenges. "Like other technologies," he writes, finance "developed through innovations that improved efficiency. It is not intrinsically good or bad." Implicit in this analysis is the conviction that the problems that financial innovations were historically invented to solve are primarily, or even exclusively, technical in nature. They are the problems of how to produce, exchange and consume scarce resources most efficiently. They can be cleanly separated, that is to say, from any political aspect: the eternal dilemma of who should get what, and why. In Goetzmann's view, money and other payment technologies, for example, evolved to facilitate exchange, and so a more efficient allocation of goods across space. The institutions of debt and interest, meanwhile, were invented to enable those who had surplus resources now to lend them to others until they needed them at some future time - making more efficient the allocation of resources over time. It goes without saying that there is a venerable tradition of economic thought that argues that this is not the case. One does not have to be a hard-core Marxist to entertain the idea that finance is not, and did not evolve as, a neutral tool to improve the operation of the free market - itself an ethically colorless state of nature in human relations. This alternative view is in perfect agreement that finance is indeed one of the most powerful tools for the organization of human activity ever invented. But it holds that it arose historically, and continues to be used today, to codify and enforce relationships built on power and luck as much as to facilitate voluntary and rational decision-making. I n my view, it is important to take this alternative perspective seriously, because it is difficult to explain the history of finance without it. Goetzmann's masterly overview itself provides many examples of ingenious financial innovations that have notably not succeeded in changing human behavior, despite being better technical solutions to the problems at hand. His erstwhile Yale colleague, the mathematician Benoit Mandelbrot, long ago showed that the conventional model of asset pricing systematically underestimates the likelihood of catastrophic volatility - and offered a more realistic alternative. Another, the economist Robert Shiller, won a Nobel Prize for proposing new types of insurance instruments that would enable households to mitigate the impact of economywide recessions and real estate crashes. Perhaps most significantly of all, the American Social Security system is almost universally acknowledged to be unsustainable in its current form - and countless well-reasoned proposals exist for its reform. Yet banks still use unreliable asset pricing models; households remain at the mercy of aggregate booms and busts; and Social Security continues to glide merrily toward its doom. Seek the reason for the failure of the ingenious financial solutions that have been proposed, and it is difficult not to detect the hand of vested interests, or indeed simply the sheer inertia of a gridlocked congressional system. "Money Changes Everything" - I agree, but politics changes even money itself. Finance is a sort of master technology, from which basic habits of mind derive. FELIX MARTIN is a partner at 1167 Capital and the author of "Money: The Unauthorized Biography."

Copyright (c) The New York Times Company [June 19, 2016]
Review by Kirkus Book Review

A financial economist's view of credit, investment, speculation, and other matters of the pocketbook.The study of finance is traditionally the finest layer of dust on the stack of arid tomes devoted to the dismal science. The Cyndi Lauper echo of the title aside, Goetzmann (Finance and Management/Yale School of Management; co-editor: The Origins of Value: The Financial Innovations that Created Modern Capital Markets, 2005, etc.) doesn't exactly shift the discussion into pop territory. However, his book is more accessible than many in the field, positing that the instruments of finance have done more than their share to make civilized life possible. The author invites us to consider that a principal effect of finance is to travel in time: that is, finance "reallocates economic value through time," linking present and future while also shifting the burden of risk to allow investors and states to do such things as build infrastructure. Finance also involves an increase in social complexity, requiring alphanumeric language for record-keeping and bureaucrats to keep track of things, so that finance is responsible for state-building. Among the earliest financial documents we have, writes Goetzmann, are clay tablets recording impossible debts denoted by absurdly gigantic numbers: "The ability to imagine and then to express such vast quantities," he writes, "would not have been possible without the leap of mathematical abstraction in the Uruk period." So, too, with Chinese record-keeping systems involving great quantities of grain offered in tribute by great numbers of people. Throughout, in perhaps an accidental theme, Goetzmann's narrative offers numerous examples of the inequalities wrought by financial systems, whether the medieval practice of "tax farming" or the speculative schemes floated by a well-known Founding Father. Of considerable interest is the author's brief closing look at future possibilities for financial regimes, such as a sovereign wealth fund to bolster some version of social security. For the numerate and fiscally wonky, an accessible survey that does a fine job of reallocating past, present, and future. Copyright Kirkus Reviews, used with permission.

Copyright (c) Kirkus Reviews, used with permission.